Bid-Rigging Remains Focus of DOJ Antitrust Criminal Enforcement: Businesses Need to Ensure Their Compliance

Sills-Cummis-Gross-607x84

A number of recent U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Division (“Antitrust Division”) press releases highlight the agency’s ongoing criminal enforcement initiatives regarding hard-core antitrust violations such as bid-rigging. Businesspersons often seem to forget that the nation’s antitrust laws carry both civil and criminal penalties. Provisions of both the Sherman Antitrust Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7) and Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27), the primary federal antitrust statutes, include significant criminal penalties that can be imposed against violators. The statutes do not state what specific violations should result in criminal penalties or the factors to be used in determining when such penalties apply. However, historically, the Antitrust Division (which has exclusive responsibility for criminal enforcement of the federal antitrust laws) has focused its criminal enforcement efforts on so-called hard-core per seviolations of Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act (15 U.S.C. § 1). The recent Antitrust Division press releases announcing guilty pleas, convictions and sentencings of individuals involved in hard-core antitrust violations suggest that the Antitrust Division is, and will be, aggressively pursuing such criminal enforcement, especially regarding the financial industry, for at least the next several years.

Criminal Penalties For Hard-Core Antitrust Violations Are Substantial

Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act prohibits contracts, combinations and conspiracies in restraint of interstate trade or commerce. The maximum criminal penalties for corporations and individuals under this statute are substantial:

Every person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $100,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $1,000,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding 10 years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court.

15 U.S.C. § 1. Although the maximum $100 million fine for corporations and $1 million fine for individuals may seem stiff enough, the Antitrust Division has also obtained larger maximum fines by arguing that 18 U.S.C. § 3571(d) allows the maximum fine to be increased to twice the gain derived from the violation or twice the loss suffered by the victims if either amount is greater than the statutory maximum.

The Antitrust Division’s 2012 fiscal year (which ended on September 30, 2012) proved to be a record-breaking year regarding criminal fines. The Antitrust Division obtained criminal fines of $1.1 billion in FY2012, the second time it had topped the $1 billion mark since 2003 (the other time was FY2009 when the Antitrust Division obtained criminal fines of $1 billion). The figure for the recently ended fiscal year rises to approximately $1.35 billion when other monetary remedies that the Antitrust Division has obtained, such as disgorgement, restitution and other penalties, are included. In the past two years, the Antitrust Division has been pursuing these other so-called “equitable monetary remedies,” more aggressively. In FY2009, the Antitrust Division filed 72 criminal cases. In FY2012, it filed 67 criminal cases, down from 90 in FY2011. Thus, it is clear that the Antitrust Division is aggressively pursuing, and obtaining, larger fines and monetary remedies against antitrust violators.

In addition, the Antitrust Division has announced that the average prison sentence it has obtained for criminal antitrust violations has been increasing. For fiscal years 2010-2012, the average prison sentence obtained has been 25 months, up from 20 months for fiscal years 2000-2009 and 8 months for fiscal years 1990-1999. In terms of total prison days sentenced, the increase is from an average of 3,313 days for fiscal years 1990-1999, to 12,722 for fiscal years 2000-2009, to 23,398 for fiscal years 2010-2012. Thus, the Antitrust Division has also been successful in obtaining longer prison sentences for individuals who have engaged in per se antitrust violations.

In light of the increasing magnitude of the criminal penalties for hard-core antitrust violations, both corporations and businesspersons must be zealous in their efforts to avoid practices that run afoul of the antitrust laws, especially hard-core per seviolations of Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act that prohibits contracts, combinations and conspiracies in restraint of trade.

Bid-Rigging Is A Per Se Antitrust Violation Often Leading To Criminal Enforcement

So-called per se antitrust violations are practices that historically have been shown to result in harm to competition. They are practices that require little or no economic analysis to determine their negative impact on consumers and/or the competitive process. These violations normally include price-fixing, bid-rigging, and customer or market allocations – i.e., agreements among two or more competitors to eliminate the competition among them so that the participants often obtain higher prices for their products or services.

Bid-rigging is the very antithesis of what should be a competitive bidding process. The entity holding the bidding process – often federal, state, or local governments – is attempting to obtain the best bid (in terms of prices, services, quality, etc.) by soliciting bids from competing providers. It would seem to be common sense that such competitors should not collude or agree to subvert the bidding process by coordinating their bids in some fashion so that the outcome is skewed toward the conspirators’ desired result. However, as the Antitrust Division’s recent press releases show, bid-rigging is still a common practice in some industries. Bid-rigging conspiracies can take many forms, including (i) certain competitors agreeing not to bid so that the conspirators’ chosen competitor will win the bid; (ii) certain competitors submitting purposely inflated bids to give the appearance of a competitive bidding process; and (iii) the conspirators rotating which competitor will be the low bidder. No matter the form, the goal of almost all bid-rigging schemes is that the participants hope to ensure the winning bidder is their chosen participant and the elimination of competition among the conspirators regarding the bidding process.

Obviously, given the nation’s economic woes in recent years, the pressure to maximize profits and secure business can lead businesspersons to make poor decisions regarding their business practices, but certain of the recent enforcement actions have related to bid-rigging conspiracies that took place over numerous years, including prior to the current economic downturn. Whether it is the familiarity with their competitors that businesspersons often gain after years of pursuing the same customers and contracts, or the importance of each long-term or financially sizable contract that is being pursued, businesspersons still engage in bid-rigging practices at a level that it would seem they should not, given the substantial criminal penalties (and prison time) they, and their companies, face for such practices.

Recent Bid-Rigging Enforcement By The Antitrust Division

Just since August 2012, the Antitrust Division has announced convictions, guilty pleas and sentencings regarding bid-rigging practices in several industries, including bidding for contracts for the proceeds of municipal bonds, public foreclosure auctions, municipal tax lien auctions, and the automobile anti-vibration rubber parts industry. The investigation and prosecution of bid-rigging conspiracies often involve joint efforts by the Antitrust Division, the FBI and the U.S. Attorneys’ Office. Indeed, regarding the first three industries – municipal bonds, public foreclosure auctions, and municipal tax lien auctions – the enforcement actions were the result of President Obama’s Financial Fraud Enforcement Task Force “created in November 2009 to wage an aggressive, coordinated and proactive effort to investigate and prosecute financial crimes.”http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2012/290188.htm. The Task Force includes “more than 20 federal agencies, 94 U.S. attorneys’ offices and state and local partners, . . . [and] [o]ver the past three fiscal years, the Justice Department has filed more than 10,000 financial fraud cases against nearly 15,000 defendants including more than 2,700 mortgage fraud defendants.” Id. Such inter-agency coordination at the federal, state and local level highlights the aggressive nature of the efforts to identify and prosecute financial crimes, including criminal antitrust violations such as bid-rigging schemes.

Foreclosure Auctions

The Antitrust Division has obtained guilty pleas from numerous real estate investors who participated in separate bid-rigging conspiracies (taking place at various times from 2001 to 2010) at public foreclosure auctions, including agreeing not to bid against one another and selecting a designated winning bidder or agreeing to bid at suppressed prices, in Alabama, North Carolina and Northern California. The Antitrust Division has stated that such conspiracies “cause financial institutions, homeowners and others with a legal interest in rigged foreclosure properties to receive less than the competitive price for the properties.” http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2012/290188.htm.

Municipal Bonds

The Antitrust Division obtained the conviction of at least six former financial services executives for their participation in conspiracies related to bidding for contracts for the investment of municipal bond proceeds and other municipal finance contracts. The conspiracies took place from 1999 through 2006 and involved collusion by financial institutions regarding investment agreements offered to state, county and local governments and agencies that the government entities used to raise money for public projects. The Antitrust Division alleged that the conspiracies resulted in the government entities’ obtaining non-competitive interest rates for the investment agreements that cost them millions of dollars.

Municipal Tax Lien Auctions

The Antitrust Division obtained the guilty plea of a Pennsylvania corporation that participated in a conspiracy to rig bids for the sale of tax liens auctioned by municipalities throughout New Jersey. From at least 1998 through 2006, the conspirators allocated bids such that the winning bidder obtained a higher interest rate for the tax lien, to the detriment of the homeowner who had failed to pay property taxes. The Antitrust Division has obtained 10 guilty pleas from the ongoing investigation.

Automobile Anti-Vibration Rubber Parts

The Antitrust Division has obtained guilty pleas, or agreements to plead guilty, from nine companies and 12 executives as a result of an ongoing investigation regarding price-fixing and bid-rigging in the automobile anti-vibration rubber parts industry. As part of a conspiracy that took place from at least 2005 through 2011, the conspirators agreed, in part, to submit noncompetitive bids for parts contracts.

Regular Antitrust Training And Rigorous Oversight Are the Key To Avoiding Violations

These recent enforcement actions and ongoing investigations highlight the need for companies and businesspersons to be knowledgeable about the antitrust laws and vigilant in their compliance with these laws. In light of the significant criminal penalties for corporations and individuals stemming from bid-rigging violations of the antitrust laws, companies should increase their training and oversight of their employees with responsibility for competitive bidding processes. Regularly scheduled training sessions should emphasize the types of unlawful bid-rigging practices that violate the antitrust laws. In addition, companies should perform regular audits of their bidding efforts and the bidding-related activities of the businesspersons responsible for such bids. Such audits should include a rigorous review of entertainment and expense reports that might indicate meetings with businesspersons from competitors that may lead to, or be in furtherance of, anticompetitive bid-rigging conspiracies. The cost of lax oversight may be significant for the company and its employees.

This article appeared in the January 2013 issue of The Metropolitan Corporate Counsel.  

Copyright © 2012 Sills Cummis & Gross P.C.

FTC Raises Hart-Scott-Rodino Thresholds

An article about the FTC was recently published in The National Law Review and was written by the Antitrust Practice of Morgan, Lewis & Bockius LLP:

 

As of the effective date (on or about February 23, 2012) transactions must be valued in excess of $68.2 million to be subject to the preclosing notification requirements of the Hart­Scott­Rodino Act.

The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has announced that it will raise the Hart­Scott­Rodino Act (HSR Act) jurisdictional and filing fee thresholds. Any transaction closing as of February 23, 2012 (or, if different, the effective date, which may be a few days after February 23, 2012) will be subject to the revised thresholds. The new rules include an increase in the “size of transaction” test from greater than $66 million to greater than $68.2 million-which means that under the new threshold, acquisitions valued for HSR Act purposes at $68.2 million or less will not require preclosing filing and approval.

New Jurisdictional Thresholds

As a general rule, the HSR Act requires both Acquiring and Acquired Persons (as defined in the HSR Act) to file notifications if the following post-adjustmentjurisdictional thresholds are met:

1.         One person has net sales or total assets of at least $13.6 million.

2.         The other person has net sales or total assets of at least $136.4 million.

3.         As a result of the transaction, the Acquiring Person will hold an aggregate amount of stock and assets of the Acquired Person valued at more than $68.2 million.

-OR-

4.         As a result of the transaction, the Acquiring Person will hold an aggregate amount of stock and assets of the Acquired Person valued at more than $272.8 million, regardless of the sales or assets of the Acquiring and Acquired Persons.

Conditions 1 and 2 are generally referred to as the “size of person” test, while conditions 3 and 4 are commonly described as the “size of transaction” test.

The HSR Act rules relating to acquisitions of partnership interests and membership interests in a limited liability company (LLC) remain the same. Only acquisitions of economic control in an LLC or partnership may be reportable. “Control” is defined as having a right to 50% or more of the profits of a partnership or LLC or 50% or more of the assets upon the dissolution of such entity.

New Filing Fee Thresholds

Filing fees are also determined by a threshold test relating to the size of the transaction. While the valuation thresholds have changed, the fees themselves have not been adjusted:

 

Valuation of Transaction Filing Fee
in excess of $68.2 million or greater, but less than $136.4 million $45,000
$136.4 million or greater, but less than $682.1 million $125,000
$682.1 million and greater $280,000

The figures above represent the new “as adjusted” threshold figures. The table below illustrates the changes.

 

Current Threshold
(in millions)
“As Adjusted”
Threshold
(in millions)
$13.2 $13.6
$66 $68.2
$131.9 $136.4
$263.8 $272.8
$659.5 $682.1

These changes are being implemented pursuant to the 2000 amendments to Section 7A of the Clayton Act. Section 7A(a)(2) of the Clayton Act requires the FTC to revise the jurisdictional thresholds annually, based on the change in gross national product, in accordance with Section 8(a)(5). The revised thresholds will apply to all transactions that close on or after the effective date.

Copyright © 2012 by Morgan, Lewis & Bockius LLP.

Football and Antitrust Law: American Needle v. NFL and It's Meaning for Combinations in Restraint of Trade and the Rule of Reason in the 21st Century

Posted in the National Law Review on November 30th an article by the  Winner Winter 2011 Student Legal Writing Contest, Michael Sabino of Brooklyn Law School regarding  the commonality of antitrust law and the NFL:

 

NFL football.  And antitrust law.  What, if anything, do they have in common?  A great many things, one might say.  Both conjure up images of powerful contestants vying for control on the field of play.  Each participant utilizing its skills, its knowledge, and its intuition to gain an edge and dominate the game.  Competition in its purest form.  Unless somebody cheats, of course.

But rules —- that is why we must have rules.  Otherwise competition descends into chaos, battle descends into barbarism, and injuries inevitably follow.  Football, for all its controlled violence, has rules that must be followed.

In the realm of business, and the controlled violence we call “competition,” antitrust law provides these rules, in large part to keep the game fair and provide the proverbial level playing field.  Thus, even from this small comparison, we can see that professional football and antitrust law have something in common, after all.[1]

Now add to the aforementioned confluences the recent Supreme Court decision inAmerican Needle, Inc. v. National Football League, et al.,[2] where the underdog, a maker of sporting apparel, decided to challenge on antitrust grounds the loss of its right to manufacture league-sanctioned hats and headwear.  Given that the high Court’s decision lacked finality, this case has not yet reached the level of a Super Bowl victory.  Nonetheless, it is akin to a playoff win that well positions the upstart hatmaker on the road to a possible upset win over what is arguably America’s best organized and most formidable sports league.

The first half of this Article will introduce, in pertinent part, the essentials of antitrust law relevant to understanding the Supreme Court’s decision, including a brief overview of the preceding landmarks that formed the basis of the Justices’ ultimate ruling.

The second half of the Article shall be devoted to the actual “play by play” of the Court’s decision, and how it was arrived at.  And just like any given Sunday, the conclusion will mimic a postgame report as to what this decision means, and where do the contestants go from here.  But far more important, a forecast for what American Needle means, for the business of sports other than football, and the business of business itself, shall be the coda.  That said, it is time for the kick off.

I.

ANTITRUST LAW – THE BASICS

Antitrust law did not evolve in a vacuum.  Quite to the contrary, it is deeply entwined with American history, its roots going back to the progressive President Theodore Roosevelt, and his goal of stamping out or at least curtailing the monopolistic business practices that so dominated late-Nineteenth Century America.[3]

Antitrust law in the United States essentially begins with the Sherman Act, promulgated in 1890.[4]  The Sherman Act was intended to be a “comprehensive charter of economic liberty aimed at preserving free and unfettered competition” by assuring that natural competitive forces interact freely, without manipulation or restraint.[5]

The Supreme Court has been steadfast in regarding the Sherman Act as akin to a common law statute, and, in interpreting that body of law, the federal courts act more as common law courts than in other areas governed by federal statute.  This is so the antitrust law “adapts to modern understanding and greater experience… to meet the dynamics of present economic conditions.”[6]

Its three foremost weapons against restraint of trade are firstly Sections 1 and 2 thereof.  Section 1 explicitly prohibits “[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or, conspiracy, in restraint of trade.” [7]  Section 2, in turn, makes illegal any monopoly or attempt to monopolize.[8] But the true weapon of mass destruction found in the antitrust arsenal is the provision for an award of treble damages to prevailing private plaintiffs.[9]  Since the singular focus of this Article is Section 1, as exposited by American Needle, henceforth the following analysis shall be limited to that statutory prohibition.

It is essential to remember that the Sherman Act “prohibit[s] only unreasonable restraints of trade.” [10]  It is axiomatic that Section 1 outlaws “only restraints affected by a contract, combination, or conspiracy.”[11]

To be certain, Section 1 liability has been limited to concerted conduct for nearly a century.[12]  Therefore, it maintains a fundamental distinction between concerted and independent action.[13]  The penultimate question is then whether allegedly anticompetitive conduct stems from independent decisions or from an agreement between otherwise distinct actors.[14]

The federal courts have judiciously employed Section 1 to condemn business combinations or more nefarious conspiracies that unlawfully restrain competition.[15]  Basic prudential concerns relevant to Section 1 enforcement are premised upon the reality that exclusive contracts are commonplace, and therefore any firm with a modicum of market power that enters into such an exclusionary accord risks an antitrust suit.  The unacceptable and unjustified risk of such a litigious free-for-all must be counterbalanced against the real need to ensure vigorous and freely competitive markets via judicious and rational enforcement of  the provisos of Section 1.[16]

For these reasons, combinations such as joint ventures have always been adjudged under the Rule of Reason.[17]  As we shall see below, the Rule of Reason has assured the sensible enforcement and adjudication of the antitrust laws for over a century now.

An icon of antitrust law, historically as well as jurisprudentially, is of course Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States.[18]  Ironically for this Article, we cite this case nearly on the day of its centennial.  And as well discussed in the last one hundred years, Standard Oil caused the breakup of the insidious Rockefeller oil monopoly, only in recent decades to see the once independent “Seven Sisters” turn back the clock via merging into the handful of “supermajor” oil companies left on the American scene.[19]

In pertinent part, the legal truisms of Standard Oil are easily related to Section 1 enforcement.  The Justices of that era declared that the statute “should be construed in the light of reason.”[20]  To be certain, said the high Court, Section 1 is not aimed to interrupt all collaboration in business; rather, its explicit and rightful goal is to protect the free flow of commerce “from contracts or combinations… which would constitute an interference with, or an undue restraint upon [commerce].”[21]  And to achieve a just and sensible result when enforcing the statute, Standard Oil decreed that “the standard of reason which had been applied at common law should be applied in determining whether particular acts [are] within its prohibitions.”[22]

Not surprisingly, such fidelity to reason extends to the remedies to be accorded when Section 1 is violated.  As characterized by the Standard Oil Court a hundred years ago, the specific remedy to an unlawful combination is two-fold: first, enjoin the continuation of the offending behavior; and two, abolish the combination or conspiracy, so as to rob it of its unlawful power.[23]  In dispensing this remedy, the Supreme Court cautioned, courts must consider the actual results of their decrees, and therefore refrain from inflicting serious injury on the public by a needless and deleterious interference with commerce.[24]

And in a final, precautionary reminder, Standard Oil confirms that the objective of American antitrust law is never to deprive business of the power and the right to make “normal and lawful contracts,” but instead solely to restrain malefactors from engaging in illegal combination or conspiracies aimed at the unlawful restraint of trade.[25]

In closing out this section of our discussion, it is only appropriate to end with a final word on The Rule of Reason from the legendary Justice Brandeis, who provided the classic formulation of the Rule of Reason in Chicago Board of Trade:[26]

The true test of legality is whether the restraint imposed is such as merely regulates and perhaps thereby promotes competition or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition.  To determine that question the court must ordinarily consider the facts peculiar to the business to which the restraint is applied; its condition before and after the restraint is imposed; the nature of the restraint and its effect, actual or probable.  The history of the restraint, the evil believed to exist, the reason for adopting the particular remedy, the purpose or end sought to be attained, are all relevant facts.  This is not because a good intention will save an otherwise objectionable regulation or the reverse; but because knowledge of intent may help the court to interpret facts and to predict consequences.[27]

The foregoing primer on antitrust law now concluded, we can turn to the actual Supreme Court decision in American Needle, and how it represents the newest landmark in this important, century-old field of law.

II.

GAME TIME: AMERICAN NEEDLE VS. THE NFL

At the time of this writing, American Needle has attained outsized prominence, partly for reasons we shall discuss below.  Much of that has to do with the prime defendant, the NFL.  And given the enormous popularity of professional football in the United States today, only a brief exposition of the relevant facts is necessary.

The National Football League (“NFL”) includes 32 separately owned professional football teams, each with its own distinctive names, colors and logos, as well known to millions of fans.[28]  In 1963, the constituent clubs organized National Football League Properties (“NFLP”), an unincorporated entity, to develop, license, and market their intellectual property.  From its inception until 2000, NFLP granted nonexclusive licenses to a number of vendors, permitting them to manufacture and sell apparel adorned with team logos.[29]  American Needle was one of those licensees.[30]

All this changed at the end of 2000, when the teams voted to authorize NFLP to enter into exclusive licenses, and NFLP then granted such an exclusive deal for 10 years to Reebok International Ltd.  Reebok now had the sole right to manufacture and sell trademarked headwear for all 32 NFL teams.  As a direct consequence, NFLP did not renew American Needle’s nonexclusive license.[31]

Understandably chagrined, American Needle filed an antitrust action against the NFL and others, alleging that the exclusive contracts violated Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act.[32]  As their key defense, the NFL, the teams, and NFLP replied that they constituted a single economic enterprise, and therefore were incapable of conspiring to restrain trade within the meaning of Section 1.[33]

On this singular question, the district court sided with the league, concluding that the NFL and its constituent members comprised a single entity.[34]  The Seventh Circuit affirmed, finding, inter alia, that football can only be carried out jointly, and the league can function only as one source of economic power when presenting NFL football.[35]   But it was not “game over” just yet.  Certiorari was granted,[36] and the matter came before the high Court.

Delivering the final opinion of his storied career, Justice John Paul Stevens[37] began by reciting the language of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, in that every contract, combination or conspiracy in restraint of trade is illegal under American antitrust law.[38]  But the first question to be asked is “whether an arrangement is a contract, combination, or conspiracy” before inquiring if it unreasonably restrains trade.[39]

Writing for a unanimous Court, Justice Stevens framed the precise issue here as that “antecedent question” in relation to the NFL and its formation of NFLP to manage its intellectual property.[40]  Wasting no time, the Supreme Court declared that the league’s action “is not categorically beyond the coverage of [Section] 1,” and the legality — or lack thereof — “must be judged under the Rule of Reason.”[41]

Having posited and then answered the question before it in such a delimited fashion, the Court confirmed that it had but one, narrow issue to adjudicate; whether the NFL and its affiliates were a single enterprise or, conversely, were independent actors capable of contracting, combing or conspiring in restraint of trade, as such activity is defined by the Sherman Act.[42]

Invoking the hallowed distinction the Sherman Act makes between Sections 1 and 2, the Court reminds that the former only applies to concerted action that restraints trade.  In contradistinction, the latter covers both concerted and independent action, but only if that action monopolizes or threatens to monopolize, by definition a narrower category than restraint of trade.[43]

In the high Court’s view, this stricter oversight for concerted behavior is rooted in Congress’ recognition that joint action is inherently fraught with anticompetitive risk.[44]  Moreover, since concerted action is but a “discrete and distinct” category of endeavor, restricting that segment only leaves unmolested “a vast amount of business conduct.”[45]

Thus, opined Justice Stevens, action done in concert is easier to examine, and easier to remedy.  Indeed, the high Court has judged collaborative action much more harshly.[46]  But of course the inquiry must be made as to whether the actors are in fact working in concert, and to that the Court now turned.[47]

To find concerted action “does not turn simply on whether the parties involved are legally distinct entities.”[48]  Justice Stevens set out the Court’s long held view disregarding overly formalistic distinctions, instead relying upon “a functional consideration of how the parties … actually operate.”[49]  Mere labels do not persuade, said the learned Justice, but the reality of identities can and should motivate the Court’s deliberations.[50]

Therefore, business organizations that hold themselves out as formally distinct actors can still be encompassed by Section 1’s oversight.[51]  It is the rule, posited Justice Stevens, rather than the exception, for the Court to look beyond the form of a purported single entity when nominal competitors come together to form professional organizations or trade groups.[52]

Function rules over form, declared Justice Stevens, and a functional analysis is justified by the Sherman Act’s goal of regulating substance, unswayed by mere formalisms.[53]  Calling upon the landmark of Copperweld, the American NeedleCourt adhered to the axiom of substance over form in determining if an entity is capable of conspiring pursuant to Section 1.[54]

Justice Stevens found it a misconception to describe such an inquiry as simply asking if the alleged malefactors are a single entity.  No one merely asks if it “seems” like the parties are one or independent in any metaphysical sense, observed the Court.[55]  “The key,” according to Justice Stevens, is whether the concerted action “joins together separate decision makers.”[56]

Putting a finer point upon the inquiry is to ask if there is a contract, combination or conspiracy amongst individual economic units who would normally be pursuing individual economic interests.[57]  If the accord between these entities deprives the marketplace of independent decisionmaking and chills the diversity of separate entrepreneurial interests, then it is violative of the antitrust law.[58]

Summarizing this portion of the opinion, the high Court emphasized that “the inquiry is one of competitive reality,” and not artificial formalisms.[59]  The conjoining of formerly legally distinct entities under a single label is not a bulwark against appropriate inquiry.[60]

The paramount question, declared American Needle, is whether the former independence of once distinct centers of decisionmaking is compromised into something lacking the normal vigor of competitive business.[61]  If so, the actors so united now have the capability to conspire in violation of Section 1, and it is then appropriate for courts to decide “whether the restraint of trade is an unreasonable and therefore illegal one.”[62]

Against these rubrics, the Justices now turned to the controversy before them.  Without equivocation or apology, the unanimous Court found that “[d]irectly relevant to the case, the [NFL] teams compete in the market for intellectual property.”[63]  Whenever each team licenses its valuable logos and trademarks, it is not acting for the league’s greater good.  Quite to the contrary, each franchise is motivated solely by its own corporate aims to enhance individual wealth.[64]

With a reference specific to the case at bar, here American Needle’s disenfranchisement from the lucrative ballcap manufacturing trade, Justice Stevens invoked the imagery of the then-reigning Super Bowl contestants.  “[T]he [New Orleans] Saints and the [Indianapolis] Colts are two potentially competing suppliers of valuable trademark…. [t]o a firm making hats.”[65]  In making business decisions as to who to grant such remunerative licenses to, each club is an independent economic entity pursuing individual economic interests.  A fortiori, each team is capable of making independent business decisions.[66]

Therefore, from all this the Court reached the inescapable conclusion that “[d]ecisions by NFL teams to license their separately owned trademarks collectivelyand to only one vendor … depriv[e] the marketplace of independent centers of decisionmaking.”[67]

In this context, the high Court made short shrift of the NFL’s defense that, by incorporating NFLP as a single entity to market the entirety of the league’s intellectual property as a unitary whole, the actors escaped antitrust scrutiny.  It is not dispositive, opined Justice Stevens, that those competitors on the field of play combined on the field of business to organize a fresh legal entity to market their valuable logos and colors.[68]

“An ongoing [Section] 1 violation cannot evade [Section] 1 scrutiny simply by giving the ongoing violation a name and label,” said the Court.”[69]  Indeed, in once again declaring that in antitrust cases form can never subdue substance, the Justices remind in one voice that condoning such facile labeling could condemn antitrust law to impotence.[70]

To be sure, the high Court acknowledged that “NFL teams have common interests” in promoting the league as a unified brand.  Nevertheless, the clubs “are still separate, profit-maximizing entities, and their interests in licensing team trademarks are not necessarily aligned.”[71]

Justice Stevens went on to characterize the teams’ common interests in the league’s brand as a partial unification of their separate economic agendas, “but the teams still have distinct, potentially competing interests.”[72]  And therein lies the danger, heldAmerican Needle, for reason that “illegal restraints often are in the common interests of the parties to the restraint, at the expense of those who are not parties.”[73]  Such harm to others is precisely what the antitrust law is designed to prohibit.[74]

The Supreme Court continued by taking up the Seventh Circuit’s view that “without [the teams’] cooperation, there would be no NFL football.”[75]  The high Court acknowledged this element of the league’s defense, duly noted that some degree of collective action is inherent to the NFL’s business, as well as in taking the field of play.  Nonetheless, the Justices found the appellate tribunal’s reasoning unpersuasive.[76]

Here Justice Stevens coined an analogy sure to be enshrined in the pantheon of antitrust jurisprudence.  The learned justice posited that “a nut and bolt can only operate together, but an agreement between nut and bolt manufacturers is still subject to [Section] 1 analysis.”[77]  Wisdom for the ages, to be sure.  Thus,American Needle declared unequivocally that while the teams may work in unison in some sense, they are surely not immune from antitrust scrutiny when they do collaborate economically.[78]

Given this conclusion, it was but a short step for the high Court to likewise declare NFLP subject to inquiry pursuant to Section 1, “at least with regards to its marketing of property owned by the separate teams.”  The Justices based that holding upon the fact that the promotional entity’s licensing decisions are made by 32 potential competitors, each of which is the actual owner of its share of this jointly managed intellectual property.[79]

Decisive here, indicated the Court, is that if NFLP had never been created, “there would be nothing to prevent each of the teams from making its own market decisions” with regard to their trademarked apparel businesses.[80]

From this analysis of what the licensing entity is capable of (and, conversely, what its existence forestalls the clubs from doing individually in competition with each other), the Supreme Court ruled that “decisions by the NFLP regarding the teams’ separately owed intellectual property constitute concerted action.”[81]  Justice Stevens sharply refuted the notion that the league members acting through NFLP is akin to components of a single entity meshing to create a collective profit.  In actuality, foundAmerican Needle, the 32 football teams retain independence, operate as individual profit centers, distinct from each other and NFLP, and are at least potential (if not actual) competitors.[82]

To be sure, the Supreme Court reached this holding with a view towards preserving the integrity of the antitrust laws.  The Justices hypothesized that if potential competitors could share profits or losses in a joint venture without worry of Section 1 inquiry, “then any cartel could evade the antitrust law simply by creating a joint venture to serve as the exclusive seller of their competing products.”[83]  The high Court made clear that it would never permit colluding parties to circumvent the antitrust laws by acting through the artifice of some straw third-party or a so-called joint venture.[84]

Drawing to the end, Justice Stevens offered some words of comfort to the NFL and others similarly situated.  Certainly, ‘[f]ootball teams that need to cooperate are not trapped by antitrust law.”[85]  A “host of collective decisions,” such as scheduling and then producing games, “provides a perfectly sensible justification” for concerted action without needless fear of incurring Section 1 liability.[86]  To discern sensible, neutral joint action as opposed to unlawful restraint of competition, the Supreme Court pledged that the axiomatic and flexible Rule of Reason would be applied, explicitly to the football league, and, implicitly, to others similarly situated in the world of sport business, as well as business in general.[87]

Finally, having refined and then applied the parameters of concerted action subject to Section 1 scrutiny, and having confirmed the proven Rule of Reason is to be the yardstick for evaluating same, the Supreme Court reversed the holding below, and cleared the path for the case to continue on remand.[88]  And so ended the Supreme Court’s newest landmark of antitrust law.

III.

ANALYSIS & COMMENTARY

We now come to the concluding portion of this Article, the customary analysis and commentary upon the case that has been the subject under discussion.  Before proceeding, however, circumstances call for the issuance of a caveat.

Certainly, and as well noted above, American Needle is, technically speaking, an interlocutory decision.  It lacks finality, as it makes no decision as to the ultimate winners and losers in the subject litigation.  It is a preliminary decision, one that sets the rules, and remands to the lower courts for further determinations consistent with its holdings.

As candidly noted at its outset by Justice Stevens, American Needle is delimited to a threshold inquiry, here, what concerted action is subject to Section 1 scrutiny.  But this self-imposed limitation of the question presented does not diminish one bit the vigor and the precedent-setting aspect of this new holding.

It can well be said that threshold determinations often presage the outcome of an entire case.  Opening the door to further inquiry, as American Needle unquestionably does here, might be all that is needed to turn the tide of battle in favor of one side.  At the least, the guarantee of further litigation compels a change in tenor for both sides: akin to a turnover of ball possession, the NFL, seeking a quick dismissal, has had its hopes dashed.  The plaintiff American Needle may now renew its offensive, and all that comes with it.

As with so many notable Supreme Court edicts, American Needle of today may prove to be the last time these contestants take the field before the high Court.  Thus, the Justices’ decision might prove to be the first, and the last, contemporary word on the case at bar.  There then is a reminder not to underestimate the importance of this holding to the field of antitrust law, its supposed preliminary nature notwithstanding.

Let us now proceed to the more sanguine elements of our analysis, and placeAmerican Needle in perspective.  Our first point is timing, as purely a happenstance as that may be.

We noted early on how this Article is written more or less on the centennial of that most famous of American antitrust cases, that of Standard Oil.  Ironically, American Needle has been, in most likelihood, the most quoted and publicly visible antitrust ruling of the Supreme Court since the turn of the last century.  We would be hard pressed to think of an antitrust case decided since Standard Oil that has consumed as much newsprint and garnered as much notoriety in the popular press as the instant case.  The reason for that is well known.

At the time of this writing, the NFL owners and the NFL Players’ Association (the “NFLPA,” distinguished, to be sure, from NFL Properties as discussed herein) have been embroiled in an epic labor dispute.  We need not provide a citation here, since this struggle has been reported daily on the front of the sports page (if not the main page) of every media outlet in the nation.  It is an apt demonstration of the American psyche, that with all of the pressing issues of the day about the Recession, the price of gasoline, and health care, just to name a few, so much ink is spilled on coverage of whether or not there shall be NFL football this year.

As is equally well known, American Needle is mentioned in nearly every news article on football’s labor strife, been the subject of radio and television sports talk, and has thereby captured the attention of the general population like few other Supreme Court cases.  Among other examples, various pundits have offered it in support of the players, relied upon it as exposing the supposed vulnerability of the NFL to antitrust claims, and cited it as evidence that judicial intervention may ultimately decide if there will be a football season.

To be sure, this is a nonsubstantive observation.  But the inescapable point remains that the public’s awareness of American Needle is far more attenuated than the vast majority of Supreme Court cases.  Be that as it may, however, the paramount concern of this Article is legal substance, so to that we now turn.

Having noted above the public’s fascination with American Needle vis-à-vis professional football, of what note has or should the NFL take of the high Court’s decision?  A great deal, one would say, and not just because the underlying antitrust action is alive and well.  Obviously, how the NFL markets its intellectual property in the years to come will be largely determined by the final outcome (be it in court or via settlement) of the instant case.  But there is much more.

As in all modern professional sports, the NFL engages in concerted action on a number of fronts, not just marketing its team logos for hats and tee shirts.  Two that immediately come to mind are television broadcast rights and the drafting of collegiate players into the professional ranks.  While those aspects of professional football’s business are far too intricate to make a worthwhile comparison here, the undeniable point remains, and it is that the NFL shall henceforth be deemed to be a collection of independent economic forces that, from time to time, band together and act in economic concert in order to enhance their corporate profits.

Given such, when these formerly independent economic actors band together and act as one, American Needle makes plain that they have thus deprived the marketplace of the free competition brought about by maintaining separate centers of financial autonomy.  That step taken, the teams cannot escape antitrust scrutiny, pursuant to Section 1 at the least, when they engage in joint endeavors.  Put in football terms, it is early in the season.  As the “game changer” of American Needle takes firmer hold within the federal courts, it remains to be seen who will emerge the victor, the league or its opponents.

The above is one emerging issue for the NFL.  What of the other leagues in the business of sports?  One need not be a legal scholar to rightly conclude that they have the same exposure.

The other professional associations, whether in the acknowledged major American sports or the ones of lesser stature, all have operating characteristics similar to that of the NFL, in one form or another.  Generally, each individual competitive team willingly accedes its rights as an independent economic actor, and collaborates with its on-the-field rivals in joint endeavors aimed at increasing each constituent’s profits.

To be sure, the case law predating American Needle, and this new landmark itself, make plain there is a safe harbor for appropriate collaboration.  Once again, Justice Stevens echoes high Court landmarks of years past in acknowledging that presenting professional sporting events requires cooperation.  The Supreme Court has long acknowledged that league sports intrinsically need to cooperate and take concerted action in order to function.[89]  Clearly, there shall be no break in that continuity.

American Needledoes nothing to upset the truism that a team cannot play itself.  Thus, all leagues in all sports can proceed with general confidence that not every collaborative action will subject its members to an antitrust lawsuit.  That is as it has always been, as it should be, and it shall clearly remain so.

Nonetheless, all professional sports leagues must proceed mindful that American Needle is as applicable to badminton as it is to NFL football.  Each and every professional league must take due note that when collaboration exceeds the boundaries of what is essential and appropriate to put on an exhibition of their sport, and crosses the line into a stifling of competition, to the injury of others, then antitrust scrutiny shall be next week’s opponent.  And unlike a regularly scheduled game, the teams do not profit when playing inside a staid courthouse.

As we alluded to early on in this writing, the field of sports is often a metaphor for the field of business.  The similarities abound, and we Americans are oft times guilty of borrowing the strategies and tactics of one, and applying them to the other (and this interchange, most certainly, works in both directions).  What then, does American Needle  portend for American business, not the business of sports to be sure, but the business of business, be it high-tech, low-tech or anywhere in between?

Not to be unduly repetitive, but the firm conclusion is that the lessons remain the same.  Competing businesses may not play in an organized “league,” and they may not sell team jerseys with the name of your favorite CEO on the back, but they most certainly do compete.  Yet sometimes they put aside their competitive fervor, to act for their common good in trade associations or as lobbyists, to deal with common problems, or to act in concert in certain combinations or joint ventures.  And that is where business lines up on the field against American Needle and its teammates, also known as legal precedents.

Here are the headlines for American business generally, as drawn from American Needle.  First, what some might characterize as the “bad news,” or at least the one with potentially negative implications for some of the players:  just as in professional football, combinations that rob the free market of independent centers of competing economic interests are illegal.

At a minimum, those that submerge their competitive vigor in return for collaboration open the doors wide to antitrust scrutiny pursuant to Section 1.  Such examination, accompanied by the threat of treble damages under the Sherman Act, might be enough by itself to drive such noncompetitors from the field of play.  To be sure, bad for them, but good for competition.

Businesses, regardless of what their precise occupations are, must hereafter be mindful that joint ventures, combinations and other forms of concerted action can expose them to antitrust liability.  They are on notice to monitor their collaborations accordingly, and scrupulously avoid any conspiratorial urges that might fatten their bottom lines at the expense of normal competitive forces.

If that is the bad news, one must candidly admit it is not all the bad, for at the least it is merely today’s iteration of the laws of antitrust that have ruled for at least a century.  In sum, no one is really changing the size and shape of the playing field.  Potential malefactors confront, more or less, the same law and penalties that they always did.  In that regard, the news is only bad if you were intent on violating the law.

That said, let us turn to the good news.  American Needle maintains the same consistency within antitrust jurisprudence that has abounded for over a century.  It is beyond cavil that business hates uncertainty more than anything else.  By reaffirming tried and true maxims, this latest Supreme Court landmark maintains that much valued consistency, and business can act accordingly and with certitude that the rulebook has not been altered from seasons past.

Next, this latest pronouncement acts in defense of full and fair competition.  The American economy, probably more so than any other in the world, is profoundly based upon free competition.  This is reflected in our laws, in our history, and indeed in the very mindset of how we conduct business in these United States.

American Needlecontinues and reinvigorates this rich and storied tradition, by giving paramouncy to the fostering of free and unfettered competition.  American businesses have always worked within this framework, and this new case encourages them to continue to do so, and with confidence that free competition will not be compromised.

American Needlefurthermore reaffirms the notion that not every combination is bad.  Business, quite naturally, sometimes draws competitive forces together, whether by contract, joint action or via some other form of mutually beneficial combination.  That, by itself, is not evil, and today’s case says so.  Justice Stevens makes clear that the law has always reserved its scrutiny for joint ventures that truly act to restrain competition, in this case the elimination of nominal and healthy competitive forces by restraining these erstwhile combatants from truly engaging each other in the marketplace.

That unification leads to our next point, that of actors usually engaged in stiff competition who, shall we say, strip off their opposing colors and join under one banner for concerted action.  In this and all other respects, American Needle confirms the long held and undeniably just maxim that substance rules over form.  Mere labels have no sway in antitrust cases, nor should they, says the high Court.

As in the preceding century, the next hundred years of antitrust jurisprudence will exalt the substance of any subject activity over the mere accident of its form.  For those whom the substance of their business activity conforms to the laws fostering free competition, that is good news.  Conversely, it is only detrimental to those who would attempt to cloak their lawbreaking ways under the guise of a meaningless label.  Put in sports terms, it does not matter what jersey you wear; it is what you do on the field of competition that counts.

Now to our last, and possibly the greatest, point of American Needle.  As described above, the Rule of Reason has dominated the process of antitrust analysis since the law’s inception well over a century ago.  We need expend few words to affirm the rightness and sagacity of that precept.  Suffice to say that truly free enterprise is a cathedral of rationality, of decisions made for good reason, and not based upon emotion, ideology nor other factors.

Therefore, the law overseeing same, and seeking to justly assure that the market remains free and fair to all participants, should likewise, in the main, examine its doings in the light of that same reasonability.  In its own way, American Needle is the modern implementation of Chief Justice Hughes’ maxim that “[realities] must dominate the judgment in antitrust cases.”[90]

In sum, American Needle does more than just declare the Rule of Reason is applicable to the case at bar; its fundamental adjudication confirms the ongoing and essential role of such a mode of analysis in all such cases to come.

Conclusion

 

In conclusion, American Needle has gone from making headlines in the field of law to now the field of professional football.  It affirms that even the obvious need for collaboration in the business of the NFL has its just limits, those boundaries to be measured by the nation’s longstanding antitrust laws.  So too for other professional sports, and so too for the rest of American business.  But in doing so, we find the Supreme Court affirming basic notions that not all collaboration is illegal, rather only concerted action that unlawfully drives out competition.  Tried and true rules, above all the proven and just Rule of Reason, will dominate the field when measuring such actions for their propriety.  It is still early in the game, but American Needle makes certain that, in the end, the real winner will be justice.[91]

[1] Over a half-century ago, the Supreme Court declared that the NFL falls “within the coverage of the antitrust laws.”  Radovich v. National Football League, 352 U.S. 445, 448 (1957) (Clark, J.) (holding baseball’s antitrust exemption inapplicable to professional football).  See also Brown v. Pro Football, Inc. dba Washington Redskins, 518 U.S. 231, 233 (1996) (Breyer, J.) (dealing with “the intersection of… labor and antitrust laws” in the context of professional football).  Professional basketball and boxing also fall under the purview of the antitrust laws, to name but a few sports.  See Haywood v. N.B.A., 401 U.S. 1204 (1971); U.S. v. International Boxing Club of New York, 348 U.S. 236 (1955).  Of all the major American sports leagues, only Major League Baseball (“MLB”) enjoys an exemption from the antitrust laws.  To appreciate the rich but convoluted history of the immunity enjoyed by the National Pastime, see Federal Baseball Club of Baltimore, Inc. v. National League of Professional Baseball Clubs, 259 U.S. 200, 209 (1922); Toolson v. New York Yankees, Inc., 346 U.S. 357, 357 (1953); Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258, 282-84 (1972).

[2] __ U.S. __, 130 S.Ct. 2201 (May 24, 2010) (hereinafter “American Needle” at 130 S.Ct.).

[3] See Edmund Morris, THEDORE REX (Random House 2001).  In this, the second of three installments chronicling the life of America’s twenty-sixth Chief Executive, Roosevelt’s preeminent biographer Edmund Morris devotes substantial discussion to President Roosevelt’s determination to utilize the still nascent Sherman Act to curb the monopolistic practices then prevalent in the American economy, for instance, Roosevelt’s initiation of the groundbreaking Northern Securities case.  THEODORE REX, inter alia, at 88-89, 314-316, 427-28; See Northern Securities Co. v. U.S., 193 U.S. 197 (1904) (pluralityopinion), cited by Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 761 n.4 (1984).  See also Northern Securities, 193 U.S. at 361 (Brewer, J., concurring in the result) (proposing the Rule of Reason in order to contain the antitrust laws within the walls of rationality in a free enterprise system).

[4] See Anti-Trust Act of July 2, 1890, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209.

[5] Northern Pacific R. Co. v. U.S., 356 U.S. 1, 4-5 (1958), quoted by N.C.A.A. v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 104 n. 27.

[6] Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 885-87 (2007).

[7] 15 U.S.C. § 1.

[8] 15 U.S.C. § 2.

[9] 15 U.S.C. § 15(a).

[10] N.C.A.A. v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 98 (1984)(Stevens, J.); State Oil Co. v. Kahn, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997); Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5 (2006) (Thomas, J.).

[11] Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 775 (1984),  cited by Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 553 (2007) (while substantively an antitrust case, Twombly has become the modern age’s preeminent holding on the pleading standard for federal cases).

[12] U.S. v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919), cited by Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 775-76.

[13] Monsato Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 761 (1984).

[14] Twomblysupra, 550 U.S. at 555, quoting Theatre Enterprises, Inc. v. Paramount Film Distributing Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 540 (1954).  See also Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 769.

[15] Seee.g. Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977);Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238-39 (1918).

[16] See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 82 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam).

[17] See Continental T.V., Inc.supra, 433 U.S. 36 (1977); Chicago Board of Trade,supra, 246 U.S. 231 (1918).

[18] 221 U.S. 1 (1911).

[19] See Wysocki, “The Progeny of Standard Oil,” Wall Street Journal (Wednesday, December 2, 1998) at p. B1 cl. 4.  See also Lavelle, “Rockefeller’s Revenge,” U.S. News & World Report (December 14, 1998) at p. 27 cl. 1 (charting and discussing the disassembly of the Rockefeller empire into the colloquially known “Seven Sisters” of the U.S. oil industry, and detailing how the “merger mania” of the 1990s drove them to reunite, leaving essentially only three surviving siblings (ExxonMobil, BP, and Chevron).

[20] Id. at 1.

[21] Id. at 3.

[22] Id. at 3.

[23] Id. at 3-4.

[24] Id. at 4. Cf.  Business Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 724-26 (1988) (Rule of Reason presumed to apply in Section 1 cases).

[25] Id. at 4.

[26] Supra, 246 U.S. 231 (1918).

27] Id. at 238, cited by American Needle,  supra, 130 S.Ct. at 2217 n. 10.  See alsoLeegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 885-87 (2007);National Soc. of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 688-91 (1978).

[28] American Needlesupra, 130 S.Ct. at 2207.

[29] Id.

[30] Id.

[31] Id.

[32] Id.  The NFL is no stranger to antitrust litigation.  In addition to the cases citedanteseee.g.United States Football League v. N.F.L., 842 F.2d 1335, 1340 (2d Cir. 1988) (affirming the famous jury verdict whereby the NFL, although found guilty of violating the antitrust laws, had to pay only one dollar to the defunct upstart USFL).

[33] Id.

[34]Id., citing American Needle, Inc. v. New Orleans Louisiana Saints, 496 F. Supp. 2d 941, 943 (N.D. Ill. 2007), affirmed sub nom., 538 F.3d 736 (7th Cir. 2008), reversed and remandedsupra, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010), where Senior District Judge Moran found that “in the jargon of antitrust law…. [the NFL teams] so integrated their operations that they should be deemed to be a single entity.”

[35] Id. at 2207-08, citing American Needle Inc. v. National Football League, 538 F.3d 736, 737 and 744 (7th Cir. 2008) (Kanne, J.) (holding intrinsic nature of NFL football “requires extensive coordination and integration between the teams,” and thus “the NFL teams are best described as a single source of economic power when promoting NFL football through licensing the teams’ intellectual property”).  But compare Fraser v. Major League Soccer, L.L.C., 284 F.3d 47, 55-56 (1st Cir. 2002) (Boudin, C.J.) (“Single entity status for ordinarily organized [sports] leagues has been rejected in several [of the] circuits.” (summarizing  cases).

[36] Id. at 2208.

[37] Of the then-sitting Justices, no one was better suited to the task at hand than Justice Stevens.  Before his appointment to the nation’s highest court, he was renowned as an antitrust law attorney and scholar.  The only other Justice who might have been a worthy candidate to craft this opinion was the by-then-retired Justice Byron “whizzer” White, who was the high Court’s only member to have achieved stardom as a collegiate football player.  See Biskupic, “Justice Stevens to Retire from the Supreme Court,” (April 12, 2010) USA Today.  See also Biskupic, “Stevens Ascends to His Final Day on Bench,” (June 27, 2010)  USA Today.

[38] Id. at 2006.  See 15 U.S.C. § 1.

[39] Id.

[40] Id.

[41] Id. at 2206-07.

[42] Id. at 2208.

[43] Id. at 2208-09, citing Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 777 (abolishing so-entitled “intraenterprise conspiracy” theory).  See also 15 U.S.C. § 1 and § 2.

[44] Id. at 2209, citing Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 768-69 (“This not only reduces the diverse directions in which economic power is aimed but suddenly increases the economic power moving in one particular direction.”).

[45] Id. at 2209.

[46] Id., citing Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 768.

[47] Id.

[48] Id.

[49] Id.

[50] Id., citing U.S. v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350, 353 (1967).

[51] Id. at 2209-10, citinginter aliaN.C.A.A.supra, 468 U.S. 85 (1984).

[52] Id. at 2210 (footnotes omitted).

[53] Id.

[54]Id. at 211, citing Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 773 n. 21.

[55] Id. at 2211-12.

[56] Id. at 2212.

[57] Id., quoting Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 769.  Copperweld was limited to the very narrow question of whether a parent corporation and its wholly owned subsidiary were capable of conspiring in violation of Section 1.  Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 767.  The Court there declared no, because “the coordinated activity of a parent and its wholly owned subsidiary must be viewed as that of a single enterprise” for Section 1 purposes.  Id. at 771.  Noteworthy with regard to better understanding American Needle today, consider the stress by Chief Justice Burger in writing in Copperweldthat coordination between a parent corporation and an internal division “does not represent a sudden joining of two independent sources of economic power previously pursuing separate interests,” and  thus immunizing such activity from Section 1 scrutiny.  Id. at 770-71.  As we will see, the harmlessness of the parent/subsidiary coordination in Copperweld stands in sharp contradistinction to the joint endeavors of the league and teams in American Needle.

[58] Id. (citations omitted).

[59] Id.

[60] Id.

[61] Id.

[62] Id.  In some ways, in writing for the high Court in American Needle, Justice Stevens revives the observation made in his dissent in Copperweld, whereby he questioned absenting two or more corporations from Section 1 scrutiny when “they are controlled by the same godfather.”  Copperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 796 (Stevens, J., dissenting).  Criticizing that Supreme Court of over twenty five years ago for not confronting the question, Justice Stevens took a step towards answering it in his penultimate opinion as a Justice.

[63] Id. at 2213.

[64] Id. at 2213.

[65] Id.

[66] Id.

[67] Id.  (quotations omitted) (emphasis supplied).  See also Areeda & Hovenkamp, VII ANTITRUST LAW 2d ed. at  ¶ 1478a, at 318 (unquestionably, the most pernicious threats to competition arise when actual or potential competitors join forces in a joint endeavor).

[68] Id.

[69] Id.

[70] Id.

[71] Id.  Furthermore, while allowing there is some similarity between the NFL and a single enterprise that owns several pieces of intellectual property which chooses to license them jointly, that outward similarity is wholly undercut here because in “the relevant functional sense” the NFL’s constituent teams compete against each other for revenue from intellectual property as much as they vie for dominance on the field of play.  Id.

[72] Id. (citations omitted).

[73] Id.

[74] Id.  Here, the Court quickly disposed of another of the NFL’s defenses, that it had marketed its intellectual property in this unitary fashion for some time.  The Court’s unanimous rejoinder: “a history of concerted activity does not immunize conduct from [Section] 1 scrutiny.”  Id. at 2213-14.

[75] Id. at 2214.  Seesupra, 538 F.3d at 737 and 744.

[76] Id.

[77] Id. (emphasis supplied).

[78] Id.

[79] Id.

[80] Id. at 2214-15.  Parenthetically, we acknowledge the Court’s observation that the law “generally treat[s] agreements within a single firm as independent action on the presumption that the components of the firm will act to maximize the firm’s profits.”  Id. at 2215.  Notwithstanding that convention, the Court allowed that in “rare cases” said presumption must be discarded, such as where intrafirm agreements impact economic interests wholly apart from the firm itself.  Section 1 scrutiny is therefore called for when such an intrafirm agreement is merely “a formalistic shell for ongoing concerted action.”  Id. at 2215.

[81] Id. at 2215.

[82] Id.  The Court widened the gap separating NFLP from league members, finding the former to be an instrumentality of the latter, with regard to licensing decisions.  Id.  Clearly this separation undergirds the holding that the NFL, the teams, and NFLP are actors with distinguishable economic interests, and were taking concerted action in licensing their intellectual property.  Id.

[83] Id., quoting Major League Baseball Properties, Inc. v. Salvino Inc., 542 F.3d 290, 335 (2d Cir. 2008) (Sotomayor, J., concurring in judgment) (internal quotations omitted).

[84] Id. at 2215-16.

[85] Id. at 2216.

[86] Id.

[87] Id.  See also Brownsupra, 518 U.S. at 252 (Stevens, J., dissenting).  Presaging his opinion for the majority in American Needle, there Justice Stevens advocated applying the Rule of Reason in benchmarking the NFL’s activity vis-à-vis the league’s potential for restraining the market.

[88] Id. at 2217.

[89] See N.C.A.A.supra, 468 U.S. at 101-02, quoting R. Bork, “The Antitrust Paradox” 278 (1978).

[90] Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.S. 344, 360 (1933), quoted byCopperweldsupra, 467 U.S. at 774.

[91] As of this writing, recent events in professional football have ordained an extraordinary role for the precedents cited above.   See Brady, et al. v. National Football League, et al., 11 CV 00639 (SRN) (D. Minn.), a class antitrust action brought by professional football players against the NFL and its constituent teams, seeking, inter alia, monetary damages and injunctive relief.  Complaint at p. 48-50.  In pleadings headlining Super Bowl winning quarterbacks Tom Brady, Peyton Manning, and Drew Brees, the players charge the league with engaging in “group boycotts, concerted refusals to deal and price fixing,” alleging same as per se violations of Section 1 of the Sherman Act.  Complaint at Para. 4, page 3.  Most pertinent to this Article, the plaintiffs allege these actions “constitute an unreasonable restraint of trade under the rule of reason.”  Id.   Thus, we witness two of the linchpins of the foregoing discussion as being highly determinative in this new lawsuit.  And so,American Needle may yet prove to be the catalyst for a day of reckoning for the NFL and the players.

Michael Sabino @ Copyright 2011

Ninth Circuit Finds Grocers’ Revenue-Sharing Agreement Must Go Through Full Rule of Reason Check-Out

Recently posted in the National Law Review an article by attorney  Scott Martin of Greenberg Traurig, LLP regarding Sitting en banc and affirming a district court decision, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit recently held:

Sitting en banc and affirming a district court decision, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit recently held in California ex rel. Harris v. Safeway, Inc.,[1]that an agreement among four large competing Southern California supermarket (“chains”) to share revenues during a labor dispute was neither protected from antitrust scrutiny under the non-statutory labor exemption nor so inherently anticompetitive as to be condemned per se or evaluated under a truncated “quick look” test. Rather, the agreement — which reimbursed to a chain targeted by a strike an estimation of the incremental profits, for a limited period of time, on sales that flowed to the other chains in the arrangement as a consequence of the strike — was subject to traditional rule of reason analysis, balancing any legitimate justifications against any substantial anticompetitive impacts.

Dissenting in part, Chief Judge Kozinski (joined by Judges Tallman and Rawlinson) stated that the majority’s “groundbreaking” ruling on the inapplicability of the non-statutory labor exemption was “very likely an advisory opinion,” and had “no basis in the record, common sense or precedent.”

The case arose from circumstances surrounding 2003 labor negotiations between local chapters of the United Food and Commercial Workers (UFCW) union and three of the supermarket chains that, with the union’s consent near the expiration of the labor contract, formed a multi-employer bargaining unit to negotiate. Along with the fourth chain (which also had a labor agreement that expired within months), the supermarket chains entered into a Mutual Strike Assistance Agreement (MSAA). The MSAA provided that if one of the chains was targeted for a selective strike or picketing (a so-called “whipsaw” tactic by which unions increase pressure on one employer within a bargaining unit), the other chains[2] would lock out all of their employees within 48 hours. As part of the MSAA, the chains also entered into a revenue-sharing provision (RSP), under which any of them that earned revenues during a strike or lockout above their historical shares relative to the other chains would pay 15 percent of those excess revenues to the other chains in order to restore their pre-strike shares.[3]

After negotiations with the UFCW broke down, a strike ensued. Picketing was focused on only two of the chains in the bargaining unit, and lasted for approximately four-and-a-half months. The two picketed chains ultimately were reimbursed under the RSP to the tune of approximately $146 million.

While the strike was underway, the State of California filed suit, claiming that the RSP was an unlawful restraint of trade under Section One of the Sherman Act.The grocers sought summary judgment on the ground that the RSP was immune from Sherman Act scrutiny pursuant to the non-statutory labor exemption, which shield certain restraints from Sherman Act challenge in order to allow for meaningful collective bargaining. The State also sought summary judgment on the grounds that the provision was unlawful per se, or should have been analyzed under an abbreviated (“quick look”) analysis. The district court denied both motions, and the parties pursued a streamlined appeal, after agreeing to a stipulated final judgment for defendants under which the State would not pursue the theory that the RSP was unlawful under a full rule of reason analysis, and the grocers would not pursue their affirmative defenses other than the non-statutory labor exemption.

On appeal to the Ninth Circuit, the original panel (in an opinion by Judge Reinhardt, who dissented in part[4]from the later en banc opinion that requires a full rule of reason analysis) considered the history of profit-sharing arrangements and the circumstances and details of the chains’ arrangement, applying a “quick look” analysis of sorts, and concluded that the RSP was likely to have an anticompetitive effect. The Ninth Circuit panel rejected the application of the non-statutory labor exemption, and also found that “driving down compensation to workers” as a consequence of the agreement did not constitute “a benefit to consumers cognizable under our laws as a ‘pro-competitive’ benefit.”[5]The Circuit then agreed to hear the case en banc.

In the en banc decision, the majority declared that “novel circumstances and uncertain economic effects” of the RSP required “open discovery and fair consideration of all factors relevant under the traditional rule of reason test,” thus approving the district court’s original determination of the proper standard. The Ninth Circuit majority acknowledged that application of the full test was “not a simple matter,” but concluded that “[g]iven the limited judicial experience with revenue sharing for several months pending a labor dispute, [it could not be said] that the restraint’s anticompetitive effects are ‘obvious’ under a per se or quick look approach.” The court distinguished the RSP from other profit-pooling arrangements subject to stricter scrutiny on the grounds that, by its terms, the RSP (i) was effective only for a limited and unknown duration, thus arguably preserving incentives to compete during the revenue-sharing period; and (ii) did not include all participants in the relevant markets, leaving other competitors in the market who could discipline pricing.

However, the majority then opined that the RSP was not entitled to protection from antitrust analysis under the non-statutory labor exemption. In so doing, the court distinguished the supermarket chains’ RSP from the agreement among a group of NFL teams to unilaterally impose terms and conditions from a lapsed collective bargaining agreement that was considered in the U.S. Supreme Court’s decision in Brown v. Pro Football, Inc.518 U.S. 231 (1996) (holding that the non-statutory labor exemption may extend to an agreement solely among employers). The Ninth Circuit majority determined that revenue-sharing is not an accepted practice in labor negotiations with a history of regulation; does not play a significant role in collective bargaining; is not necessary to permit meaningful collective bargaining; does not relate to the “core subject matter of bargaining” (wages, hours and working conditions); and restricts a business or “product” market, not a labor market.

Because the State of California had stipulated to a dismissal in the event that it did not prevail on a categorical basis under a per se or quick look analysis (which it did not), Chief Judge Kozinski wrote in dissent that the majority had in effect written an impermissible advisory opinion, and had gone “out of its way to rule on thenon-statutory labor exemption.” Chief Judge Kozinski went even further, however, In his view, “all of the relevant Brown factors weigh heavily in favor of exempting the RSP from antitrust review.” This was not a case of employers using a labor dispute as a pretext for price-fixing, but rather one of employers responding to union strike tactics, and then only to the degree that the tactics were effectively deployed. According to Chief Judge Kozinski, adding to strikes “the additional threat of antitrust liability — with its protracted litigation, unpredictable rule of reason analysis and treble damages — will no doubt force employers to think twice before entering into a revenue-sharing agreement in the future” and, contrary to precedent and policy, force employers “to choose their collective-bargaining responses in light of what they predict or fear antitrust courts, not labor law administrators, will eventually decide.”[6]

With the Ninth Circuit having effectively elevated the antitrust laws over the labor laws, one might postulate a fair chance of a petition for certiorari being accepted by the U.S. Supreme Court in this case implicating significant questions of both law and public policy. Unfortunately, in light of the stipulated dismissal, such review may have to wait, as the grocery chains may lack standing, let alone incentive, to seek it here.


[1]Nos. 08-55671, 08-55708 (9th Cir. July 12, 2011).

[2]The fourth chain, which was not in the original multi-employer bargaining unit, was not required by the MSAA to engage in the lockout.

[3]The RSP would be in effect until two weeks following the end of a strike or lockout, and it required the chains to submit weekly sales data for an eight-week period prior to the strike or lockout to a third-party accountant.

[4]Judges Schroeder and Graber joined in Judge Reihardt’s partial dissent.

[5]California ex rel. Brown v. Safeway, Inc., 615 F.3d 1171, 1192 (9th Cir. 2010).

[6]Quoting Brown, 518 U.S. at 247.

©2011 Greenberg Traurig, LLP. All rights reserved.

 

FTC And DOJ Issue Proposed Statement Of Antitrust Policy Regarding Accountable Care Organizations Seeking To Participate In The Medicare Shared Savings Program

Recently posted at the National Law Review by Scott B. Murray of  Sills Cummis & Gross P.C.  information about the  Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) and Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division (“DOJ”)  joint Proposed Statement of Antitrust Enforcement Policy Regarding Accountable Care Organizations:    

The Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) and Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division (“DOJ”) recently issued a joint Proposed Statement of Antitrust Enforcement Policy Regarding Accountable Care Organizations Participating in the Medicare Shared Savings Program (the “Policy Statement”). The Policy Statement details how the federal antitrust agencies will apply the nation’s antitrust laws to accountable care organizations (“ACOs”) created pursuant to the health care reform act, the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (the “Act”). Public comments were to be submitted by May 31, 2011.

The agencies identify the potential advantages and disadvantages of ACOs that they will examine under the antitrust laws. The agencies “recognize that ACOs may generate opportunities for health care providers to innovate in both the Medicare and commercial markets and achieve for many consumers the benefits Congress intended for Medicare beneficiaries through the Shared Savings Program.” Policy Statement, at p. 2. However, the agencies also understand that “not all such ACOs are likely to benefit consumers, and under certain conditions ACOs could reduce competition and harm consumers through higher prices or lower quality services.” Id.

ACOs Covered By Policy Statement

The Policy Statement applies to “collaborations among otherwise independent providers and provider groups, formed after March 23, 2010, that seek to participate, or have otherwise been approved to participate, in the Shared Savings Program.” Id. “[C]ollaboration” is defined to mean an agreement or set of agreements, other than merger agreements, thus, the Policy Statement does not apply to mergers among health care providers, which will still be analyzed under the Horizontal Merger Guidelines. Id.

The Rule of Reason Will Be Applied To ACOs

The agencies have previously stated that joint price agreements among competing health care providers are evaluated under the Rule of Reason, if the providers are financially or clinically integrated and the agreement is reasonably necessary to accomplish the pro-competitive benefits of the integration. The Rule of Reason “evaluates whether the collaboration is likely to have substantial anticompetitive effects and, if so, whether the collaboration’s potential pro-competitive efficiencies are likely to outweigh those effects.” Id., at p. 4. Thus, “the greater the likely anticompetitive effects, the greater the likely efficiencies must be to pass muster under the antitrust laws.” Id.

In prior pronouncements regarding health care provider collaborations, the agencies have stated that sufficient financial integration exists if the collaboration’s participants have agreed to share substantial financial risk, because such risk-sharing generally establishes both an overall efficiency goal for the venture and the incentives for the participants to meet that goal. The agencies have previously provided a number of examples of satisfactory financial risk-sharing arrangements, while noting that the examples did not represent an exhaustive list.

Regarding clinical integration, while not previously providing specific examples, the agencies have noted that such integration must be “sufficient to ensure that the venture is likely to produce significant efficiencies.” Id., at p. 4. The Act authorizes CMS to approve ACOs meeting certain eligibility criteria, and the Policy Statement indicates that “CMS’s proposed eligibility criteria are broadly consistent with the indicia of clinical integration that the Agencies previously set forth [and that] organizations meeting the CMS criteria for approval as an ACO are reasonably likely to be bona fide arrangements intended to improve quality, and reduce the costs, of providing medical and other health care services through their participants’ joint efforts.” Id., at p. 5. Because many health care providers will want to use the ACO structure in both the commercial market and the Medicare context, “if a CMS-approved ACO provides the same or essentially the same services in the commercial market the Agencies will provide rule of reason treatment to an ACO if, in the commercial market, the ACO uses the same governance and leadership structure and the same clinical and administrative processes as it uses to qualify for and participate in the Shared Savings Program.” Id., at p. 5. The Rule of Reason analysis applies to ACOs for the length of their participation in the Shared Savings Program.

Streamlined Approach For The Rule Of Reason Analysis Of ACOs

The Policy Statement provides a streamlined approach to determining market shares for the common services provided by an ACO’s participants. The first step is to list the common services provided by two or more of the ACOs’ participants. The list of services for the various types of health care providers ( i.e., physicians, inpatient facilities, and outpatient facilities) will be made available by CMS. The second step is to determine the Primary Service Area (“PSA”) for each common service of the ACO participants. “The PSA is defined as the lowest number of contiguous postal zip codes from which the participant draws at least 75 percent of its patients for that service.” Id., at pp. 7 & 12.

If the ACO participants do not provide any common services in any of the same PSAs, then the ACO needs to determine if any ACO participant is a “Dominant Provider,” meaning a participant with greater than 50 percent market share for a service in a PSA. If the ACO does include a Dominant Provider, such participant must be non-exclusive to ACO, and the ACO cannot require commercial payers to be exclusive to ACO or otherwise restricted in dealing with other ACOs or providers.

Safety Zone Applies If ACO Has Less Than 30 Percent Combined Market Share For All Common Services In All PSAs

If there are common services provided by two or more ACO participants in the same PSA, then the ACO must calculate its combined market share for each such common service in each PSA. CMS will make available Medicare fee-for-service data sufficient for physicians and outpatient facilities to calculate their market shares. For inpatient facilities, market shares should be calculated based on “inpatient discharges, using state-level all-payer hospital discharge data where available, for the most recent calendar year for which data are available.” Id., at p. 13. Where such data is not available, Medicare fee-for-service payment data should be used, or other available data if such Medicare data is insufficient.

If the combined market share for each common service in each PSA is less than 30 percent, then the ACO falls within the “safety zone,” meaning that there will be no agency challenge of the ACO absent extraordinary circumstances. If the combined share for even one common service is greater than 30 percent in a PSA, the safety zone does not apply.

In addition, for the safety zone to apply, any hospital or ambulatory surgery center participating in the ACO must be non-exclusive – i.e., allowed to contract or affiliate with other ACOs or commercial payers – regardless of its PSA market shares. If the ACO falls within the safety zone, but includes a Dominant Provider, then the same Dominant Provider requirements described above must be met.

An ACO may include one physician per specialty from each “rural county” (as defined by the U.S. Census Bureau), and a Rural Hospital, on a non-exclusive basis and still qualify for the safety zone even if the inclusion of the rural provider or Rural Hospital makes the ACO’s combined market share for a common service greater than 30 percent in a PSA.

Mandatory Review By The Agencies Applies If ACO Has Greater Than A 50 Percent Combined Market Share For Any Common Service In A PSA

If an ACO’s combined market share for any common service in any PSA is greater than 50 percent, the ACO must make a submission to the agencies for a mandatory initial review of the ACO’s potential competitive effects. Thus, if the combined share for even one of the ACO’s common services is greater than 50 percent in a PSA, review by the antitrust agencies is mandatory. The mandatory review requirement does not mean that the ACO is presumed to be anticompetitive, but only that an initial review is necessary.

The ACO must submit to the agencies a copy of its application and all supporting documents that the ACO plans to submit, or has submitted, to CMS or that CMS requires the ACO to retain as part of the Shared Savings Program application process. In addition, the ACO must submit other documents that will allow the agencies to analyze the ACO’s potential competitive effects. If the agencies receive all such documentation in a timely fashion, they have committed to completing the review in an expedited, 90-day time period. The additional documents that must be submitted include documents relating to the ability of the ACO’s participants to compete with the ACO, the ACO’s business strategies, competitive plans, and likely impact on prices, cost, or quality of any service the ACO provides, any other ACOs created by or affiliated with the proposed ACO or its participants, the ACO’s market share calculations, the identity of the ACO’s five largest payer customers, and the identity of any competing ACOs. Id., at pp. 9-10.

After receiving this documentation, the reviewing agency will advise the ACO within 90 days of whether it has no intent to challenge the ACO or is likely to challenge it. CMS will not approve an ACO that has received a letter of likely challenge.

No Man’s Land If > 30 Percent, But << 50 Percent Combined Share

Given the safety zone and mandatory review thresholds, there is a no man’s land for ACOs with market shares for common services that fall between these two thresholds – i.e., if the ACO has a combined market share for any common service in any PSA greater than 30 percent, but no combined market share greater than 50 percent in any PSA. While there is no presumption that ACOs falling in this no man’s land will have anticompetitive effects, the agencies have identified certain conduct that such ACOs should avoid to reduce the risk of challenge by the antitrust agencies:

1. Steering or incentivizing commercial payers away from providers outside the ACO.

2. Tying sales of the ACO’s services to the purchase of non-ACO services (and vice versa).

3. Contracting with ACO participants on an exclusive basis (except for primary care physicians, who can be exclusive to an ACO).

4. Prohibiting commercial payers from providing health plan participants with the ACO’s cost, quality or other performance information.

5. Sharing price or other competitive information among the ACO’s participants that can be used to collude regarding non-ACO services.

ACOs with market shares requiring mandatory review should also avoid such conduct to reduce the risk of antitrust challenge.

If an ACO falling within the no man’s land desires to obtain further certainty regarding whether it will face an antitrust challenge, it can request expedited antitrust review by the agencies similar to the mandatory review process.

Likely Concerns Regarding The Proposed Policy Statement

Potential public comments to the Policy Statement include:

1. Whether non-exclusivity should be required for a hospital or ambulatory surgery center if the ACO still falls within the safety zone for all common services and does not include a Dominant Provider for any service.

2. Whether the 30 percent and 50 percent market share thresholds are appropriate.

3. Are PSAs an appropriate proxy for the relevant antitrust geographic market?

4. Will the Medicare and other publicly available data allow for accurate market share calculations?

5. Will the mandatory review process represent an unreasonable time and cost burden to be incurred by proposed ACOs?

6. Should the Policy Statement include additional examples of market share calculations for hypothetical ACOs?

The Policy Statement represents a substantial and welcome effort on the part of the agencies to provide guidance to the health care industry regarding the antitrust analysis to be applied to ACOs seeking to participate in the Shared Savings Program; however, it is likely that some procedural and substantive modifications will be necessary to help health care providers fully achieve the goals of the Act through the formation of ACOs.  

This article appeared in the June 2011 issue of The Metropolitan Corporate Counsel. 

The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of Sills Cummis & Gross P.C.  

Copyright © 2011 Sills Cummis & Gross P.C. All rights reserved.

 

 

Antitrust, Intellectual Property Rights, and the Online Music Industry: An Antitrust Analysis of Apple’s Combination of Services and Products

The National Law Review would like to congratulate Rui Li of the The University of Iowa College of Law one of our Spring 2011 Student Legal Writing Contest Winners.  Rui’s topic is An Antitrust Analysis of Apple’s Combination of Services and Products:       

I.  INTRODUCTION

For many music consumers, the ideal medium for music is digital. It offers many advantages over CDs, including easier distribution, decreased physical size, greater choice in the medium of sound reproduction, and the ability to include digital data such as artistic information and graphic artwork.i Online music stores offer more variety than consumers would get in a brick-and-mortar store, including reviews, recommendations, and other interactive features which increase the choices for consumers.ii The advantages of digital music, coupled with the efficiency of online purchasing, have helped online music stores such as Apple’s iTunes Store become the most prevalent form of commercial music distribution.iii However, online music piracy has been harming the music industry via lost CD sales even before commercial distribution of music over the Internet became prevalent. As online music firms attempt to tackle online music piracy, both antitrust enforcement agencies and private plaintiffs have raised concerns. Some of the solutions implemented by online music firms appear to promote competition by protecting intellectual property rights. However, others require closer scrutiny because some actions taken to protect these intellectual property rights have been, at times, abusive.

The tactics used by Apple to combat digital piracy have drawn legal scrutiny from a number of sources in recent years. In June 2006, the antitrust enforcement agencies of Norway, Sweden and Denmark filed a complaint against Apple regarding the restrictions it placed on iTunes audio downloads, an action that was later joined by Germany and France.iv On December 31, 2007, a group of plaintiffs brought an antitrust lawsuit against Apple in the United States District Court for the Northern District Court of California, charging Apple with maintaining an illegal monopoly on the digital music market.v On December 28, 2008, the court granted plaintiffs’ motion for class certification against Apple.vi On May 25, 2010, the New York Times reported that the United States Department of Justice was examining Apple’s tactics in the market for digital music.vii In light of this scrutiny, in 2009 Apple stopped selling music downloads with its proprietary digital rights management (“DRM”) restrictions, a technology that prevented audio downloads purchased through the iTunes Store from playing on portable media players other than Apple’s iPod.viii Given the dominant position of iTunes in online music distribution, the effect of Apple’s decision to remove DRM restrictions on the online music industry and the fight against online music piracy remains to be seen.ix

Apple’s digital music business has important ramifications for antitrust law that this Note explores. Part II of this Note examines Apple’s digital music business practices with particular emphasis on the manner in which Apple combines products and services. Part III engages in an antitrust analysis of four possible causes of action against Apple’s business conduct with an eye toward the market structure of the digital music industry. The Note concludes that Apple’s combination of products and services is procompetitive, and, in addition, offers a promising solution to digital music piracy.

II.  IPOD, ITUNES AND ITUNES STORE

In 2001, Apple introduced the iTunes music software application to help music consumers organize, browse, and play digital media. In 2003, Apple launched the iTunes Store which, in April 2008, became the number one music vendor in the United States.x On February 24, 2010, the Store had its 10 billionth song download and a music catalog of over 12 million songs.xi iTunes Store now accounts for seventy percent of the worldwide digital music download retail market.xii

Until January 2009, Apple restricted iTunes Store and iTunes Software to work only with its own portable media player, the iPod, a product that currently claims 70 percent of the portable media player market.xiii Apple restricted the iPod so it could only play files embedded with Apple’s own DRM downloads called “FairPlay”, and no one else’s. Likewise, files downloaded from the iTunes Store could only be played on an iPod. Apple maintained this closed system through regular updates and the threat of legal action. Most notably, in 2005, Apple forced RealNetworks to abandon its “Harmony” technology through software updates and the threat of patent infringement lawsuit.xiv Harmony allowed music downloads purchased through RealNetworks direct playback on iPod.

III.  ANTITRUST ANALYSIS WITH AN EYE TOWARD THE MARKET STRUCTURE OF THE MUSIC INDUSTRY

As a precursor to an analysis of Apple’s conduct from an antitrust perspective, an inquiry must be made into the market structure of the music industry.

A.  The Equilibrium Between Major Labels, Online Music Vendors, and Customers

The music market is highly concentrated, dominated by a small number of large firms (hereinafter “Major Labels”: Sony Music Entertainment, Universal Music Group, Warner Music Group, and EMI Music Group). Major Labels’ collective catalogs comprise about 85 percent of the distribution rights in the music industry.xv Each of these firms has exclusive control of a large and fungible catalog of intellectual property. In the past, Major Labels have taken advantage of their dominant position to extend market power into downstream distribution channels.xvi These practices have at times drawn the attention of antitrust enforcement agencies. In 2000, the Major Labels settled the Federal Trade Commission’s charge of restraining competition in the music market.xvii

The significant economies of scale achieved through the grouping of thousands of authors’ and composers’ copyrighted music products operate as a barrier for other firms to enter the music licensing market. This concentrated market structure lays the groundwork for a tacitly collusive environment in which Major Labels can achieve collusive results in the online music market through the non-collusive exercise of their power in the licensing market. Under this tacitly collusive structure, they may be able to reach a consensus about how to develop the online music market without explicitly agreeing with each other. If one of the Major Labels sets a high and relatively profitable licensing price, the rest of the Major Labels may follow the practice of the price-setting firm even though they do not formally communicate with each other.

The appearance of online music vendors poses a threat to this shared dominant market position. Scholars estimate that Major Labels would lose thirty to forty percent of their profit margins if online music vendors could freely compete with Major Labels.xviii To protect their advantage, it is in the Major Labels’ best interest to either deny market entry to online music vendors or bring them into the fold in an advantageous manner. Fortunately for the Major Labels, this is not much of a challenge because the barriers to entry are high and the products are fungible.xix In addition, copyright laws have given Major Labels influence over online music vendors.xx Major Labels can potentially use licensing practices to create prohibitive barriers to entry or to contractually bind online music vendors to the pricing structure of the CD market.xxi Because of this market structure, online music vendors stand little chance of success competing with the traditional distribution networks established by the Major Labels over the decades.xxii

A major, common priority of Major Labels is to gain control of the digital music distribution market. To achieve this goal, in descending order of preference, Major Labels have the potential strategies of: 1) attempting to terminate online music piracy through vigorous infringement suits or other form of antipiracy enforcement measures, 2) extracting shared monopoly profits from online sales at a rate higher than or equal to that from CD sales, or 3) expanding volume of online sales at lower profit levels by licensing online music at reasonable rates.xxiii An examination of the economic theories explaining the behaviors of oligopolies lends support to the prediction of strategies laid out above.xxiv The part that follows will compare the actual practices of Major labels to the behaviors predicted above.

Strategy No.1: Terminating online music piracy through vigorous infringement suits or other form of antipiracy enforcement measures. In 2003, the Recording Industry Association of America (RIAA), the representative of Major Labels, began attacking online music piracy by filing mass infringement suits. However, this approach, besides being expensive and time consuming, backfired.xxv It not only failed to win public sympathy for the music industry but also demonized the plaintiffs, the Recording Industry Association of America and the copyright holders they represented.xxvi In light of this, the RIAA announced in December 2008 that it was ending its mass infringement suits and attempting to cooperate with Internet Service Providers whereby Internet Service Providers will suspend or terminate Internet users’ service after repeated RIAA notices of alleged piracy.xxvii

Strategy No.2: Extracting shared monopoly profits from online sales at a rate higher than or equal to that from CD sales. In 2001, Major Labels pooled their catalogs into two non-overlapping online music vendors, MusicNet and Pressplay.xxviii They refused to license music for less than two dollars per song, and, in some cases, as much as three and a half dollars.xxix In addition, the music downloads are not transferable to CDs. In 2002, the Major Labels licensed Listen.com for a price of 99 cents per song, roughly the equivalent to the price of a CD.xxx Still, most of that music could not be burned to a CD.xxxi In March 2001, U.S. Department of Justice opened an investigation into alleged collusion in the online market.xxxii However, the DOJ later dropped the investigation in 2003 because “major labels licensed their music to a broader array of third-party music services that compete on price and features” and that unrelated firm Roxio’s acquisition of Pressplay diminished the possibility of collusion.xxxiii

Strategy No.3: Expanding volume of online sales at lower profit levels by licensing online music at reasonable rates. By the end of 2002, the Major Labels had licensed their catalogs to all major online music vendors which charged a nine to ten dollars per month subscription fee, plus 99 cents per burnable download.xxxiv

During this period Apple launched iTunes Store with a market model combining iTunes Store, iTunes Software, and iPod. The combination proved to be a huge success. Apple was thus able to dispense with subscription fees.xxxv In 2008, Apple became the number one music vendor.xxxvi The entrance of a radically efficient product model, the iTunes-iPod combination, coupled with the shared interest of Apple and Major Labels in eliminating online music piracy, promoted competition, lowered costs, improved services, and increased overall economic efficiency in the music industry.

The evolution of the online music market showed that even though Major Labels’ preference of options may partially be explained as legitimate attempts to eliminate online music piracy, they still had every incentive to thwart the development of the online music market despite the fact that customers preferred music downloads. Major Labels thought the rising of the online music market and the new business models for delivering music would deprive them of their control over the market. But when they realized they were not able to stop the development of online music distribution, they attempted to control the pace and the manner of development of online music.xxxvii

Apple’s business model combines pricing, ease of use, and technical prohibition in a way that significantly decreases the incentives for customers to choose pirated music. However, it remains to be seen whether the appearance of powerful market participant such as Apple will eventually create a more competitive environment, bring down the costs of online music, and terminate online music piracy. Therefore, the courts and the antitrust enforcement agencies should understand the equilibrium between the music industry’s interest in controlling mechanisms of distribution, the threat of online music piracy, online music vendors’ interest in lowering licensing costs, and the consumers’ interest in innovative and effective access to music. The courts could consider refraining from imposing direct legal action against online music vendors such as Apple. History has shown that time and market forces often provide equilibrium in balancing interests, whether the new technology is a player piano, a copier, a tape recorder, a video recorder, a personal computer, or a MP3 player.

B.  The Alleged “Tying Arrangement” of iPod, iTunes Music Store, And iTunes Software

“Tying” occurs when a seller insists that the buyer take a second, or “tied”, product as a condition of obtaining the seller’s initial “tying” product.xxxviii Tying arrangements can be condemned either as contracts in restraint of trade under section 1 of the Sherman Act, or else under the more explicit provisions of section 3 of the Clayton Act.xxxix

Prior to January 2009, Apple had created something that resembles a tying arrangement by using its FairPlay technology to require owners of iPods to purchase digital music from the iTunes Store (users could still use music ripped from CDs or downloaded from unauthorized websites).

Tying is illegal per se when the defendant ties two separate products and has market power in the tying product.xl The “leverage” theory articulated by Justice Brandeis in Caprice was the only theory articulated by the Supreme Court supporting the per se approach. The theory understood tying arrangements as inherently anticompetitive because it permitted a monopoly firm to “leverage” its market power to a product market in which it lacked market power, increasing its monopoly profits.xli The leverage theory has largely been discredited by economists who argue that when the second product is imposed as a cost of using the first monopoly product, the monopolists are not necessarily better off because the elevated price of the tied product reduces the consumers’ willingness to pay for the tying product. It is now widely accepted most tying arrangements are procompetitive and efficient.xlii While the “leverage” theory of tying has been largely debunked, the market foreclosure theory continues to have relevance. It is now understood that tying arrangements are anticompetitive only in the rare cases that tying denies rivals access to markets.xliii However, economists have argued that this “access denial” or “entry barrier” theory is only marginally more plausible than the “leverage” theory.xliv

Courts have followed the lead of economists and become skeptical of antitrust claims based on tying theories. In the Microsoft case, the D.C. Circuit Court held that integration in the software industry involving computer operating systems promised significant efficiencies and that even relatively low-tech ties typically produce significant efficiencies by enabling firms to control the quality of collateral products.xlv The D.C. Circuit Court further concluded that the rule of reason should be applied to the Windows and Internet Explorer tie because a per se rule could act as an irrational restraint on efficiency and innovation, which often consists in combining features or functions that previously were separate.xlvi The court recognized the difficulty in distinguishing anticompetitive forced package sales from those that are efficient and effective. This is exactly the reason why a “rule of reason” analysis should be applied to all tying arrangements, the court explained.

In a “rule of reason” analysis, an antitrust enforcer proceeds by asking first whether the tying arrangement unreasonably excludes rivals.xlvii If the products are widely available separately, then there is no market foreclosure because widespread availability of alternatives indicates that no rival is foreclosed by the tie.xlviii Applying this analysis to the subject of this Note, Apple’s online music business, it is clear that alternatives to iTunes Music Store and iPod are widely available. Alternatives to iTunes Music Store include: RealNetworks, Wal-Mart, Amazon, Napster and Yahoo. In the portable media player market, alternatives to the iPod include: Microsoft, Sony, Creative, and SanDisk. Therefore, no rival is foreclosed by the tying from a properly defined market.

Courts should not substitute their own product designs for those generated by the market. Nevertheless, courts are often asked to determine whether a tying bundle is unreasonably anticompetitive. iTunes Music Store, the dominant online music vendor, needs to combat online music piracy and perform additional functions besides distributing music in order to develop the online music market. iTunes Music Store now offers customer support, a platform for customer reviews, Podcasts subscriptions, music and audio book previews, and iTunes U online service at no extra cost. A price-cutting online music vendor or online music piracy service might take advantage of the fact that Apple cannot charge separately for these services. The other vendors might charge a lower markup and refuse to provide essential services such as combating online music piracy and developing the online music market, knowing that the consumer will keep enjoying the free services provided by iTunes Store. Undoubtedly, iTunes Store cannot survive by only supplying uncompensated services that benefit other dealers. One strategy Apple can employ to minimize free riding is to tie iTunes and iPod to ensure a healthy supply of consumers who have subscribed to either iPod or iTunes.

While all these practices are readily defended as procompetitive, the defense is unnecessary in the first place when there is no injury to competition. The purchasers of iPod and iTunes bundle simply want a smaller product than the one that Apple is offering. But that desire does not harm competition. Apple’s bundle is simply the equivalent of the land developer who refuses to subdivide before selling. It is not the purpose of antitrust law to regulate the size of the products that Apple chooses to sell.

C.  Refusal To License FairPlay Patent

Apple used its FairPlay digital rights management system to require owners of iPods to purchase digital music from iTunes Store. Apple refused to license its patented FairPlay technology to other portable media player manufacturers such as Microsoft and declined to support alternative digital rights management systems such as RealNetworks’ Harmony technology that circumvented Apple’s FairPlay system. Generally, the owner of an intellectual property right does not have a duty to deal with a competitor, even if the owner refusing to deal is a monopolist, as long as there are valid business reasons for refusing to deal. In CUS, L.L.C. v. Xerox Corp., the Federal Circuit held that a “patent holder may enforce the statutory right to exclude others free from liability under the antitrust laws” in the “absence of an indication of illegal tying, fraud in the Patent and Trademark Office, or sham litigation.”xlix In addition, the patent statute contains no compulsory licensing provisions and even stipulates that there is no patent “misuse” when a patentee refuses to license its patent to competitors.l The provisions of 35 U.S.C. § 271 provide that “No patent owner shall be denied relief or deemed guilty of misuse or illegal extension of the patent right by reason of his having refused to license or use any rights to the patent.”li Although in Image Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co.lii, the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals affirmed a finding of antitrust violation where Kodak refused to sell patented products to competitors, it is now widely accepted that the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals made a significant error. In that case, Kodak refused to license its patented parts to firms that wanted to compete with Kodak in the repair of Kodak photocopiers.liii The court determined that Kodak was unlawfully creating a second monopoly in service by refusing to sell the patented parts.liv The court based its decision on the theory that under the patent laws, a patent may legally create a monopoly in only one market.lv Kodak reflects an erroneous understanding of the nature and functions of a patent. Rather than market rights, patent claims create exclusive rights in technologies.lvi A compulsory licensing of intellectual property rights is only justified where a monopolist’s refusal to license is profitable only because it tends to extend or preserve a monopoly.lvii Apple’s refusal to license its FairPlay technology to any other online music vendor and MP3 manufacturer would easily pass this test because licensing FairPlay to a rival such as Microsoft or RealNetworks would deprive Apple of both online music and iPod sales and that is always an adequate business justification. A compulsory licensing of Apple’s FairPlay technology to competitors would effectively turn Apple into a public utility and places the court in the undesirable position of price regulator.

D.  Patent Misuse

Patent misuse refers to improper acts committed by a patent or other intellectual property rights holder.lviii In 1952 and again in 1988 Congress amended the Patent Act to bring the concept of misuse more closely in line with antitrust principles.lix Congress intended to put a stop to the expansionist applications of patent misuse doctrine to reach practices which were not anticompetitive under any definition.lx For example, in Brulotte v. Thys Co., 379 U.S. 29 (1964), the Supreme Court condemned a contract under the patent misuse doctrine demanding royalty payments after the patent expired, even though there was no showing of anticompetitive practices.lxi In response to the Court’s application of the patent misuse doctrine to reach practices which are irrelevant to the concerns of antitrust law, Congress limited the use of the doctrine by providing that a patent owner is not guilty of patent misuse if it refuses to license, requires licensees to purchase goods that would work effectively only with the patent, or ties different products in the absence of showing of market power in the primary product.lxii Therefore, whether Apple’s use of FairPlay technology is a patent misuse may not have independent relevance when Congress limited its scope to antitrust violations. Thus, there is no need to make an independent inquiry as to whether Apple’s use of FairPlay technology is a patent misuse.

E.  Product Design: Strategic Creation of Incompatibility

Apple engaged in strategic creation of incompatibility by designing an exclusive combination or system of iPod, iTunes Software, and iTunes Store. Generally speaking, antitrust courts are not competent to second-guess decisions about product design.lxiii In most circumstances, the conduct that creates excessive incompatibility is also self-deterring.lxiv The market provides strong discipline for firms that produce innovations that customers reject. This suggests that truly anticompetitive product redesigns are uncommon.lxv Therefore, Apple’s regular updates to iTunes Software and iPod, which add new features as well as maintain the closed system of iPod, iTunes software, and iTunes Store are presumably procompetitive. However, Microsoft showed that a product redesign is anticompetitive if the firm has very substantial market power and the redesign is sufficient to exclude complementary products from the market.lxvi Moreover, the firm must intend the injury caused by the selection of a particular technology.lxvii In addition, the injury must greatly outweigh the benefits that the redesign produces for consumers.lxviii As explained in Part B, Apple’s redesign serves the purpose of its unique product model. It provides consumers through various updates with new features such as visual music, podcasts, playback capacities, and seamless management of music. Unlike the case in Microsoft, there is integrative benefit from combining the iTunes and iPod.

IV.  CONCLUSION

Apple’s business practices of combining services and products have raised antitrust concerns. This Note analyzed Apple’s practices with an eye toward the realities of the music market. For courts and antitrust enforcement agencies to continue to serve as competition and innovation facilitators, they need to fully understand what the structure and the landscape of the music market are and how the entrance of a new and aggressive business model such as Apple’s exclusive system alters the competitive landscape of the music market. The most serious impact of a court’s finding of antitrust violation is not the large damages awarded to the plaintiffs. Rather, it is the loss of healthy competition and the innovative and effective access to copyrighted materials. An antitrust analysis of the possible causes of action against Apple shows that Apple’s conduct may not have harmed competition after all. If balancing is required to determine whether certain restraint is anticompetitive or not, antitrust should stand aside, trusting that the market rather than the government will strike the right balance.

i Brendan M. Schulman, The Song Heard ‘Round the world’: The Copyright Implications of MP3s and the Future of Digital Music, 12 HARV. J.L. & Tech. 589, 626-27 (1999).

ii Press Release, NDP Group, Amazon Ties Wal-Mart as Second-Ranked U.S. Music Retailer, Behind Industry-Leader iTunes, May 26, 2010, available at http://www.npd.com/press/releases/press_100526.html.

iii Press Release, Apple, Inc., iTunes Store Top Music Retailer in the U.S., Apr. 3, 2008, available at http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2008/04/03itunes.html.

iv Thomas Crampton, Apple Faces Fresh Legal Attacks in Europe, New York Times, June 6, 2006, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2006/06/09/technology/08cnd-apple.html.

v In re Apple iPod iTunes Antitrust Litig., C05-00037 JW, 2009 WL 249234 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 15, 2009).

vi Id.

vii Brad Stone, Apple Is Said To Face Inquiry About Online Music, New York Times (May 25, 2010), available at http://www.businessweek.com/news/2010-05-26/justice-department-said-to-s….

viii Press Release, Apple, Inc., Changes Coming To The iTunes Store (Jan. 6, 2009), available at http://www.apple.com/pr/libarary/2009/01/06itunes.html.

ix See NDP Group Press Release, supra note 2.

x See Apple Press Release, supra note 3.

xi Press Release, Apple, Inc., iTunes Store Tops 10 Billion Songs Sold (Feb. 25, 2010), available at http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2010/02/25itunes.html.

xii See NDP Group Press Release, supra note 2.

xiii Jessica Hodgson, Leap Year Trips Zune in Black Eye for Microsoft, WALL ST. J. (Jan. 2, 2009), at A9, available at http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123074469238845927.html.

xiv Real Reveals Real Apple Legal Threat, MACWORLD(Aug. 10, 2005), available at http://www.macworld.co.uk/news/index.cfm?Rss&NewsID =12310.

xv In re Time Warner et al., F.T.C. File No.971-0070 (2000) (Statement of Chairman Robert Pitofsky and Commissioners Shelia F. Anthony, Mozelle W. Thompson, Orson Swindle, and Thomas B. Leary), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2000/05/cdpres.shtm.

xvi Greg Kot, Are We Finally Buying It?: New Model Will Change the Way Musicians Approach Craft, Chicago Tribune, May 11, 2003, § 7, at 1.

xvii See FTC Press Release, supra note 15.

xviii Matthew Fagin et al., Beyond Napster: Using Antitrust Law to Advance and Enhance Online Music Distribution, 8 B.U. J. Sci. & Tech. L. 451, 457 (2002).

xix Anthony Maul, Are the Major Labels Sandbagging Online Music? An Antitrust Analysis of Strategic Licensing Practices, 7 N.Y.U. J. Legis. & Pub. Pol’y 365, 373-75 (2004).

xx Id.

xxi Id.

xxii Id.

xxiii Id. at 373-74.

xxiv Herbert Hovenkamp et al., Antitrust Law, Policy and Procedure: Cases, Materials, Problems 290-96 (6th ed., 2009).

xxv Sarah McBride & Ethan Smith, Music Industry to Abandon Mass Suits, WALL ST. J. (Dec. 19, 2008), available at http://online.wsj.com/article/SB122966038836021137.html.

xxvi Id.

xxvii Id.

xxviii See Maul, supra note 19.

xxix Id.

xxx Id.

xxxi Id.

xxxii Id.

xxxiii Statement by Assistant Attorney General R. Hewitt Pate, Regarding the Closing of the Digital Music Investigation, (Dec. 23, 2003) available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2003/201946.htm.

xxxiv See Maul, supra note 19.

xxxv Id.

xxxvi See NDP Group Press Release, supra note 2.

xxxvii See Maul, supra note 19.

xxxviii N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5-6 (1958).

xxxix Id.

xl Id.

xli Cabrice Corp. v. American Patents Development Corp., 283 U.S. 27, 31-32 (1931).

xlii Herbert Hovenkamp, The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution 261 (1st ed., 2005).

xliii Id. at 263.

xliv Id.

xlv United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 84-90 (D.C. Cir.), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001).

xlvi Id.

xlvii Hovenkamp, supra note 42, at 265.

xlviii Id.

xlix CSU, L.L.C. v. Xerox Corp., 203 F.3d 1322, 1328 (Fed. Cir. 2000).

l Hovenkamp, supra note 42, at 265.

li 35 U.S.C § 271(d).

lii Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., 125 F.3d 1195, 1196 (9th Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 523 U.S. 1094 (1998).

liii Id.

liv Id. at 1218-1219.

lv Id.

lvi Hovenkamp, supra note 42, at 269.

lvii Id. at 270.

lviii Id. at 272.

lix 35 U.S.C. § 271(d).

lx Hovenkamp, supra note 42, at 274.

lxi Brulotte v. Thys Co., 379 U.S. 29 (1964).

lxii 35 U.S.C. § 271(d).

lxiii Hovenkamp, supra note 4, at 274.

lxiv Id. at 275.

lxv Id.

lxvi See Microsoft, supra note 45.

lxvii Hovenkamp, supra note 42, at 276.

lxviii Id.

© Copyright 2011 Rui Li